A couple events occurred last week, which are very much related, but on face value may not seem to be. Last Wednesday, Finance Minister Davendranath Tancoo presented his mid year budget review. The following day, a public holiday, Prime Minister Kamla Persad-Bissessar stood shoulder to shoulder with trade union leaders at the Labour Day platform in Fyzabad.
Given the election result and the composition of the Cabinet, this now goes beyond symbolism as labour moves forward as a coalition partner, not just campaign supporter.
The next major milestone on this journey will be the presentation of the 2026 National Budget later this year. Anyone who has meaningfully worked with budgets can attest to the fact that it is more than numbers and math. Since it involves tradeoffs, it is effectively a statement about values and the choices that are being made, in sync with those values.
In a national context, one value is that of trickle-down economics, where the rich can and should get richer to have some benefit trickle down to the the economic classes below. Then the Government steps in after the fact to plug the difference via transfers and subsidies.
Even if it is not the most palatable approach, it could have worked in an environment where revenues from abundant natural resources allowed the State to satisfy the needs of the general population while those at the top were able to benefit by “getting richer”.
Our revenue position no longer allows for that model. We must move forward to restructure our economy, so that ordinary workers/entrepreneurs understand that they have to produce and create wealth and then can capture a fair share of the wealth they create, rather than becoming tenderpreneurs or waiting for government handouts after the fact.
How can this be done?
I will start by suggesting that it’s the opposite of what we have been doing all along. Historically we treat inequality as something to fix after it happens as opposed to introducing policies aimed at preventing it from occurring in the first place. Up until now the focus has been on redistribution of income through taxes and transfers, which of course allows for political patronage at the back end of that exercise.
It requires much more work, but delivers far more benefits if we can reshape the very structure of production and corporate governance to produce opportunities and wages that flow directly from the workplace while still remaining competitive in the marketplace.
Again, I acknowledge this is easier said than done.
Malaise
Our economic structure is challenging because we have faltered on the alter of diversification. The energy sector is a major revenue contributor but employs a small fraction of workers, while the majority work in services that often have low productivity and limited growth opportunities.
This “commodity trap” leaves us vulnerable to external shocks while generating insufficient quality employment for our educated workforce. The increased allocation to education during the mid-year review of over $3 billion by itself does little if the people we are educating are not presented with meaningful job opportunities post graduation. Those opportunities have to be there before they graduate. One only needs to look at the current youth unemployment rate and interview recent graduates to understand this point.
While people are complaining about a lack of meaningful employment, trade union participation has declined to less than 20 perbcent of wage earners and is concentrated mainly in the public sector and state enterprises. Collective bargaining occurs in silos, with little sectoral coordination. Most significantly, either through poor representation or simply not being involved, workers have little voice in strategic government or corporate decisions about investment, technology adoption, or business model changes that determine their economic futures.
The traditional approach is higher taxes and expanded social programmes, leading to benefits for the unemployed and the underemployed. Again, this treats inequality after it occurs rather than providing opportunity at the start. The existing approach faces inherent limits. It stifles innovation on the one hand and it creates sub-optimal behaviours, including dependency, amongst its recipients.
Overall, it does not address the underlying structure that produces low-wage work in the first place. In our context, it also depends on energy revenues that are both finite and volatile.
We need to weight and consider changing the rules of the game for careers and for opportunity rather than redistributing income afterward. This is where the artificial intelligence discussion beings. Do we use AI to enhance labour and productivity or do we use AI to replace labour?
The former means widening the base of people and workforce opportunities, steering technology toward labour enhancing rather than labour replacing uses and giving workers meaningful voice in corporate decision making. The latter latter is about automation and the replacement of workers and affording them a universal basic income.
The labour movement has a role to play in this. Go back to when First Citizens Bank went public in 2013, the Banking, Insurance and General Workers Union took an ideologically rigid stance, warning workers that purchasing discounted shares would make them complicit in privatisation.
Workers who ignored union advice and bought shares saw substantial returns, those shares that traded at $22 in 2013 have since doubled in price and then some, along with dividends. The union’s position reflected outdated thinking that views worker ownership as betrayal rather than empowerment.
Former Prime Minister Dr. Keith Rowley began his tenure with the establishment of the National Tripartite Advisory Council. It represented recognition that economic modernisation required labour’s active participation. It didn’t last. The potential for institutional cooperation is there but the challenge is that of moving beyond adversarial relationships.
Lessons
The most successful examples of worker empowerment come from countries that have embedded labour’s voice directly into corporate governance. Germany’s codetermination system requires companies with over 2,000 employees to reserve half their supervisory board seats for worker representatives, while firms with 500 to 2,000 employees allocate one third to workers.
The results challenge conventional economic wisdom. Recent studies show German firms with worker representation have capital bases that are 40 to 50 per cent larger than those without, invest more in training and research, and demonstrate greater resilience during economic downturns. Rather than hampering competitiveness, workers’ voices appear to encourage long-term thinking and stakeholder oriented strategies.
These outcomes make economic sense. Workers have different time horizons than shareholders. A worker cannot easily diversify their human capital investments the way shareholders can diversify financial portfolios. This gives worker representatives incentives to support investments in training, research, and productive capacity that boost long-term competitiveness even if they reduce short-term profits.
Moreover, worker representatives bring operational knowledge to boardroom discussions about technology adoption, workplace organisation, and human resource strategies. This information advantage can improve decision-making quality, particularly in industries where tacit knowledge and employee cooperation are crucial for productivity.
The secret of course being, that worker representatives, have to have more skills than possessing the loudest voice and the ability to address others as “comrade”.
We can do a few things quickly and consider some others over time. The Industrial Relations Act needs updating but I will leave it to others to pronounce on the details. Beyond that I referred in my last column to the governance model of the National Insurance Board and there should be active consideration given to applying this model in the State sector and depending on its success then eventually to the corporate sector.
The combination of technology and a more mature workforce means we have to tie tax benefits to evidence of employee upskilling. The open question is - where is the incentive to invest in technology in a manner that demonstrably increases rather than reduces employment.
The key insight is that technological progress is not predetermined. Policy choices about entrepreneurship and technology, influence whether innovation complements or substitutes for human labour.
I am not here to enumerate reforms but to point out that the current political moment offers unusual opportunity for such reforms. The need for economic diversification and onshore economic development highlights the pressing need for market-driven approaches to economic development. The support of labour in the recent electoral success also provides a platform for a more inclusive approach, providing of course that labour itself is willing to recognize that their role is much more than the traditional employer-labour relations.
Just as importantly, business leaders should also recognise that the old model of cheap labour and tax incentives has reached its limits. With energy rents declining and global competition intensifying, productivity growth through active worker participation and pathways to entrepreneurship may be the only socially sustainable path forward.
Ian Narine is a financial consultant who laboured over the Labour Day weekend to produce this column. Please send your comments to ian@iannarine.com